Seth Boffeli: >> Hi, everybody. Thanks for coming out. My name's Seth Boffeli. I'm the communications director with AARP Minnesota, and really glad to have you here today. I hope everybody is enjoying our heat wave. If you're like me, you put your winter hat away today and you took out your summer winter hat. But, hey, it's always worse we're not in Atlanta where they're pestered by an inches. I don't know who it was that said the South will rise again, but I don't think they took in consideration the weather that they're having down there. But anyway, thanks for coming. We are really excited this is the second conversation we've had in the last several years with on Social Security and Medicare at the Humphrey School. We're very thankful to Larry and our partnership here. This is really a unique forum. We are very blessed to have two great leading thinkers, both from the right and the left here with us today. We're going to have an open and honest and frank, and believe it or not, humorous discussion here today about some really important programs. I think the key is it will be civil it will be not like anything that you see on TV. From our perspective at AARP, if we really want to figure out a long-term to secure future for Social Security and Medicare, conversations like this are what we really need to foster, not just in Minnesota, but in all 50 states. Before I turn it over, I just want to recognize two dignitaries from AARP. Cheryl Mathias is here in front. She is a senior policy advisor for AARP, and Joan Ruff is here, too. Joan's going to speak a little bit later, but Joan is on our national policy board. They're here in Minnesota, part of their job is really to travel the 50 states and get a sense of what our constituents, our members think on these two programs. But with that, I will turn it over to somebody who needs no introduction, at least not in this room, Larry Jacobs. Larry Jacobs: >> Thank you very much, Seth [APPLAUSE] I want to thank our partners, AARP. These are just the events we love to do substantive, civil, and important and timely that's what this is. I also want to thank all of you for coming out. I start to see the snow falling, and I wondered how many of you would brave the weather so thank you so much for coming. As Seth said, we really have two terrific people here. I want to start off with a broad question and give our guest Dean Baker and Kevin Hassett. Kevin Hassett is for me a remarkable combination. He is the American Enterprise Institute, is one of the favorite economists that Republican presidential candidates and members of Congress love to consult because he knows his economics and has also got a good feel for what might fly in Washington. He's also an economist who's really interested in a lot of these issues. It's not politics only. You see him involved in some really interesting conversations and partnerships, often with colleagues who don't see eye to eye with him on other issues. The other thing I love about Kevin is he publishes in the most exclusive journal for economists, the American Economics Review. When you think of your very best for economists, it's publishing the American Economics Review, and Kevin's able to do that. It's a remarkable accomplishment. Dean Baker's similar record of accomplishment. He is one of the most prominent economists looking at issues relating to labor, social welfare. Obviously, Social Security and Medicare, health reform. He's one of those people that Democrats in Congress and presidential candidates have on speed dial and is also remarkably prolific. These are two folks who really know their stuff. It also helps that they went to college at the same place, and by all appearances seem to like each other so that's a real benefit. Now, with that build up, I'm wondering, starting with you, Kevin Hassett, if you could give us your sense of what's going on in Washington, DC. Folks out here in the prairie scratch their heads off about the the rancorousness and the sense of not much getting done other than avoiding complete catastrophic outcomes. Can you bring us up to date on the thinking in Washington about Social Security and Medicare? What are we looking at? Kevin Hassett: >> Sure, thanks, Larry it's really a great honor to be back here. You folks, most of you live here, and so maybe you've grown accustomed to how wonderful it is here in Minneapolis and at the University of Minnesota. But it's unthinkable there aren't many places in the country where you could take two [inaudible] like me and Dean and put us on stage talking about Social Security and Medicare and get such a vibrant and full audience so I commend you. I guess it is a heat wave because there's a lot less hat hair today than there was the last time I appeared. It's great to be up here with Dean, as well. We were both Swarthmore college undergrads. We didn't know each other then you're slightly older than me, I think, isn't that right? We like to think of ourselves as the Swarthmores on that talk about economics. Actually, a start, you say, how's it going in Washington? Of course, it's an election year, and there's going to be the Punch and Judy show that we're all so used to. But I'm beginning to see things change in a way that I'm starting to sense I haven't talked to Dean about this. I'm interested to see what you have to say about this, that there's a lot more movement to try to think of stuff that folks could do together. A lot more Democrats meeting with Republicans in off the record settings. An example I could give, for example, is that the House Ways and Means Committee has been working on a corporate tax bill that could actually have a chance of moving except for Senator Baucus there's a change in leadership in Senate finance, and so he's moving out of that spot or has moved out of that spot and so that there's not much hope of moving something into a new Senate finance committee this year. But the Democrats and Republicans on the Ways and Means Committee agreed to have off the record meetings on how folks should think about corporate tax reform and the possibilities of it and what the pitfalls and the land mines and so on. They had these hearings. There were 10 of them I was at three of them, and a huge share of them members came, both parties experts or people who pose as experts were invited and the exchanges were lengthy and collegial. I'm beginning to see a lot more stuff like that. Even going back to something we talked about before that Dean and I were working on that I think that there was a turning point for me in policy and how I need to think about how to have a positive effect. Because in the end if something doesn't become law, then you've wasted your time. Not on the science part if you get a paper in a journal, it'll help someone in the future make law. But it all started really in 2009, wasn't it? That I was at a wedding and some hedge fund guy said, Why the heck is the unemployment rate so low in Germany? Their GDP dropped by more than ours, but their unemployment rate didn't. I started working on it, and then I found that they had a program that I liked so much, I thought we should emulate it, and I wrote a piece, I think for Bloomberg saying that, hey, we ought to emulate the Germans, change our unemployment insurance system. We can make it much better and more modern if we do this. Dean sent me an email and said you're right. For once, I think you might be [LAUGHTER] we should do something together so, Dean and I wrote really a couple pieces in the New York Times about this program, and then worked behind the scenes. I met with House leadership, Democratic leadership, Senator Reed of Rhode Island took the lead, and they didn't get it 100% right, but they changed the law. I think you can really trace it back to our New York Times pieces they changed the law. By finding something that people who care about the world, but view it differently, can agree on and then presenting it to people as something that's not partisan, but just a good idea that can make the world a better place. It really worked. Dean Baker: >> Quite a number of states did it, too. States adopted it because at the end of the day, the idea of word sharing is handled through state unemployment insurance laws, and each state has their and at the time we wrote about this, I think it was 22, 23 states, but at least three or four have since adopted it in each case, it's been bipartisan. Kevin Hassett: >> At the American Enterprise Institute, as the director, we have about 260 people I don't know the economic team is a big chunk of the team. We've been pouring ourselves whole hog into finding more ideas like that. If you look at, there's a young labor economist named Michael Strain, who's been thinking about how to help the long-term unemployed, and he's got lots of, I think, interesting ideas that with unidentifiable partisanship, we should subsidize people or help people move if they're unemployed. If you find a job in North Dakota, but you can't go there because it costs too much to move in North Dakota, then that's a bad thing so why don't we have relocation assistance for people who have been unemployed for a long time anyway. Those ideas are being embraced by Republican leadership in a way. It's not really public yet, but I think that there's a change that people have said, well, we can fight about the minimum wage. We can fight about the top income tax rate, and we can fight about that forever, and we probably will continue too. But why don't we spend at least a little bit of time on stuff that we can agree on and try to make it happen? Larry Jacobs: >> Kevin, let me lay out a few time markers. Ten years ago, we had President Bush who literally, probably about this point was campaigning around the country to change the structure of social security towards a partial privatization of individual accounts. I'm not hearing, and I want you to correct me if I'm wrong, those ideas about restructuring Social Security at the forefront of Washington debate, not the forefront of Republican debate. Maybe three or four years ago or less Representative Paul Ryan had some ideas about Medicare, which were, again, fairly robust and geared towards the structure of the program. I hear less about that from Mr. Ryan these days. If I understand what you're saying or the implication is that rather than going for these epic wins in terms of restructuring programs, there seems to be more of an interest in saying, what are actionable policies that you could build a bipartisan coalition around? Is that accurate? Kevin Hassett: >> That's right. On Social Security, though, I think that it's worth making a side then for actionable policies that could happen too, I definitely want to go to Dean because I don't want to talk too much, at least not yet. But the thing is about Social Security that I think it's really clear is that there were people who pushed privatization as a reform for Social Security that were not making economically literate arguments. I think that those bad arguments got crushed by trained economists and now people understand that the things that they were saying were stupid and wrong and no one's ever going to admit that. Privatization is good, in some sense, having government do it or you do it probably in the end, you controlling it is a good thing. But the argument is just I can make it really clear in a 45 second example, and that's where I'll stop. The problem is that suppose we have a world where there's a young person and an old person, and the young person puts a dollar1 in the bank or the young person earns money, and the old person doesn't the young person gives the old person a dollar every year. Then next year, the old person passed away. The young person's an old person. There's a new young person. They earn some money they give a dollar to the old person who is a young person who gave a dollar to somebody else the year before. That's Social Security, that's how it works. Well, suppose that a privatizer comes and says to the young person, hey, this isn't fair. You put in a dollar, you take out a dollar. Your rate of return is zero. Why don't you put 90 cents away today and then you'll have a dollar tomorrow, and then you'll be better off? Then the young person says, that's great let's do that they privatize Social Security. Then they look and they see this old person who thought he was going to get a dollar, and they don't have the dollar from the young person anymore because he put it in a savings account for himself, and so what are we gonna do? Let the old person starve? We'll say no, we don't. Then what we'll do is we'll borrow a dollar from the Chinese, say, give it to the old person and then pay interest on it forever, which is about 10 cents a year, and so we go and how do we pay the interest? We tax the young person 10 cents. We've gone from a system where he puts in a dollar and gets out a dollar to a system where he puts in a dollar, gets out a dollar. It hasn't really changed. But for the longest time, there were people saying, you should put in 90 cents to get a dollar. The rate of return is zero. We need to change the system I think that we've finally got them to stop. Larry Jacobs: >> This is why I love having conversations with Kevin Hassett. He's genetically wired for candor. [LAUGHTER] The harsh words he just had for partial privatization are geared to some of the folks that you sometimes advise. Kevin Hassett: >> But I support privatization, I can say, but not for the stupid reasons. There are a lot of good reasons for it. Dean Baker: But I think that the problem is that the good reasons for it are really hard to sell politically. I don't think that it's likely to move. Larry Jacobs: Dean Baker, I want to pick up this theme of economic illiteracy and focus it on how you see the current debate in Washington, which for much of the Obama presidency is focused on this idea of finding a grand bargain in which Democrats agree to make some concessions and scaling back Social Security benefits in a variety of ways, including the inflation adjuster in the context of reducing long term deficits and debt. Does that make sense? Dean Baker: It makes sense how you described it. I don't think the policy made sense. I felt we really got off on a wrong track. If you go back to where we were, we first got big deficits because the economy collapsed. Kevin's been saying some things about the Republicans. I'll say something about the Democrats. A lot of Democrats running around, George W. Bush, blew a hole in the budget, this and that, his tax cuts, the wars he didn't pay for. I wasn't particularly fond of the tax cuts. I wasn't particularly fond of the wars. But the reality was that the deficits were not especially large just before the collapse in 2008. Now, you could say we would like them to be smaller, but I can tell you exactly how long we could run the deficits that we had in 2007 forever. The debt to GDP ratio was coming down. The deficit at that point, was 1.6% GDP. We could run a deficit of 1.6% GDP forever. Anyhow you had a situation where the Democrats had exaggerated the problem of the deficit throughout the Bush years, and I think that helped to feed into this situation where, we had the economy collapse because the housing bubble burst, 2008, 2009, and we ran large deficits. You had a lot of people think, my God, we have this forever problem of really large deficits, and I think the Democrats helped to contribute to that. Reality was we hadn't had very large deficits until the economy collapsed. At that point, it was good that we had large deficits, and the basic story was very simple. When the housing bubble burst, the housing bubble was creating all this demand in the economy. Simple reasons. People were building homes in near record paces, creates a lot of demand. Secondly, all these people had equity in their homes. You just saw the price of your house double, which in a lot of places it did, and some places it tripled. Guess what? When people see the price of their house triple, well, they spend some of that. Not a stupid thing to do, especially if it's going to stay there. You got a house for 150,000, now it's worth 450,000. Well, you might buy a new car. You might take a vacation or maybe you're going to send your kid through college. It's not a bad thing to do. Problem was, it didn't stay at 450,000. It fell back to 150. What that meant was there was this huge gap in demand. We lost, my rough estimates somewhere on the order of 600 billion a year in annual demand because of the fall off in residential and nonresidential construction, and roughly the same amount on the consumption side. People saw roughly $8 trillion in housing equity disappear. They've been spending based on this wealth just disappears. That's why we had the deficit. We were making up that gap. Some of that was just the natural workings of the economy, automatic stabilizers, people lose their jobs, they pay less in taxes. We had a big fall off in tax revenue. Flip side was spending. We have programs like the Food Stamp Program, SNAP, and also unemployment insurance. Spending automatically increases when people lose their jobs, see their income fall. That was a big part of that. We did on top of that, deliberately create a larger deficit with the stimulus. That was spending money. That was the point. That was putting more money in the economy, much of it was tax cuts, and that created a larger deficit. Well, the deficits weren't always there. Large deficits weren't always there. They were there because the economy collapsed. To my view, I didn't look at this as a problem of a deficit. I looked as a problem of a collapsed economy, and the deficit was part of the solution. But suddenly, we had a lot of people running around Washington, my God, the sky is collapsing. We have these huge deficits, out of control spending, blah, blah, blah, blah, blah, blah. That created the context where, well, we have to have a grand bargain. We have to sit down, and the Democrats are going to agree to cut Social Security, cut Medicare. Republicans will agree to have some increase in taxes, and that will get our deficits down. To my view, as I say, the deficit at that time certainly was not a problem. I'd say it's not a big problem today because, again, we need demand in the economy. We're still well below full employment by almost 31% estimate. The focus on Social Security and Medicare as being the problem, as I say, I thought that was very wrongheaded because implied in the story with Social Security is that seniors have too much money, and I think for the most part, that's not true. Which isn't to say there's no one anywhere, so I'm not going to say it's absolutely sacred, but the point was, in general, I don't think Social Security is a particularly generous program, certainly, if we compare it to other countries that we think of ourselves as comparable to Canada, England. Generally, it's less generous than most of these programs. On the Medicare side, the idea that we're going to do it by cutting, if you're going to reduce Medicare costs, and I think to some extent, the Affordable Care Act is trying to pursue that. I think that's great. But if you compare the United States, the generosity of our Medicare program with other countries, it's not that we're getting more care. It's not that people in the United States are getting better healthcare, better outcomes. It's that we're paying twice as much for just about everything, for our drugs, for our doctors, for medical equipment. You go down the list. If you have a plan to save cost on Medicare, it shouldn't be by making seniors pay more, at least not for the most part. Again, I'm not going to say every penny is sacred, but it has to be focused on cutting costs. I think the idea that somehow we had to take this out of the hide of our seniors, I thought was very much misplaced. That was something I really regretted about it. Larry Jacobs: I want to just give a shout out. If you've got a question, there are cards walking around. Please fill them out. We're going to get to as many as we possibly can. Kevin Hassett, I want to pick up on a theme that has often puzzled me. When you look at the trust fund reports, nonpartisan expert report, and their best estimate in terms of Social Security, let's put aside Medicare for the second. But if you look at Social Security, what we've just heard last year is yet again, Social Security is in pretty good shape for about 20 years out to a year hopefully we'll see 2033, it's way out there. Yet, we have these discussions in Washington about the need to scale back Social Security, even though its finances, according to the trust fund, reports are good. How did this happen? How did we get so locked in with President Obama and Republicans saying Social Security was the driver of our deficits? Dean Baker: Social Security is, of course, not the driver of our deficits. Government healthcare spending is probably the biggest driver and certainly in the fullness of time, the healthcare driving engine is taking over the whole machine. I think that it's widely accepted. I don't think Dean disagree. If Dean accepts it and I accept it, then widely accepted might be true. But I think that the prescription drug benefit costs more in present value than Social Security. I've seen estimates suggest that. Maybe plausible. I've looked at that but it's so plausible. But it puts it in perspective. In shortfall. Yeah. Because it was an unfunded expenditure. In addition to the long run deficit, the present value of it from the drug benefit is bigger. Therefore, if you want to do something, you have to go after medical expenses. Social Security is a tiny fraction of the problem, but it's still a significant problem. We're talking, what about this current present value shortfall is maybe around six trillion or so, give or take a trillion among friends. Larry Jacobs: But that's out decades. That's over 75 year period. You look at it, out two decades. Actually, if you walk this back to Greenspan's commission in the early '80s, many years, we had surpluses out of Social Security that were essentially covering shortfalls in the government's general revenue pool. Now we're continuing to get these reports. The program is in good shape for two decades. The question I guess that I'm asking is, again, just focusing on Social Security, is this one of those areas that you'd put in the Kevin Hassett economic illiteracy that didn't make sense? No, you think it does make sense today. Dean Baker: I think it's really urgent that we act on Social Security. But the reason is that one, there are, I think, low-hanging fruit things like the work sharing, changes to Social Security that everybody ought to agree to, and we can go into those in a minute that need to happen now because there are negative effects, like for example, there's an extra high tax on second earners that's discouraging older females often from working. There's not much benefit from working after a certain age, and so we're discouraging people from working. Those things we could address. But in the long run, suppose that in the end, what we need to do is take folks like maybe everybody in this room, but certainly the folks on this panel, we've had pretty lucky lives, and we're not going to be living just on Social Security when we retire. Right now, we're being promised benefits 25 years from now that are richer than probably necessary, and maybe than we can afford. If you were to tell us today, well, we're not going to give you 2,000 a month, we're going to give you a 1,000 a month, 25 years from now, then we can start to plan. So that when it's 25 years from now, we'll have adjusted and we'll have saved. I think that it's urgent that we fix it on the backs of people who can afford it, some progressive indexing or something like that and we do it soon so that the people whose benefits are going to go down have a chance to optimize against the new system and change their behavior. Larry Jacobs: Great. Dean Baker, when you hear that, does that sound like a solution to the deficit problem as it's been talked about in Washington? Because everything Kevin Hassett just said makes sense. It's frankly in a roster of things that have been talked about for decades and decades, and we can add to it. But I'm still not hearing how that ties into this deficit mania that we hear in Washington. Dean Baker: Well, it makes good sense to me. No, I'm kidding. I just want to see how Kevin will react to that. Well, two things. First off, again, just to repeat that we don't really have a deficit problem today. I think that this is when I'd put in economic illiteracy that we have people running around going, my God, we have a deficit of $600 billion, and that's a huge sum because none of us will ever see $600 billion. Of course, the relevant fact here is we need a denominator, and we have an economy that's on the order of 17 trillion. We're talking about a deficit around 3.5% GDP. Again, maybe larger than you'd like, but given the fact that most of that is due to the fact we're still very much below full employment, very far from having recovered, it's not in my view at all a problem. I'd rather have a bigger deficit. If I could snap my finger and had the choice of doubling the deficit or having it, I would take double. Wait. Dean is the first Democrat to ever say, thank God, President Bush didn't pay for that Iraq war. [LAUGHTER] I said it every time. I didn't say he should fight it. But I don't blame him for not paying for it. Having said that, again, longer term problem as I think all of us agree, it is a healthcare story. Now, in looking at Social Security, to take issue with Kevin here, yes, we have some people that could take cuts in benefits, but to really affect the finances of the program, it won't just be people earning 200,000 a year. You're going to have to talk about hitting people earning 50, 60,000 a year. I get a kick out of this in Washington because when we want to raise taxes, you recall we just restored part of the Clinton a tax rates. The question was, where would you do that? Where was the cut off? President Obama originally said 250,000. Well, 250,000 is that rich? Then you end up doing it at 400,000 so it was a cutoff. Now we're talking about Social Security. Where should cut back people's benefits? Well, to really have much impact, you have to talk about and we could argue where the exact line is, but somewhere around 40, 50, 60, because the reality is, Pete Peterson, most of you probably know the billionaire who's giving a lot of money to groups to support cutting back Social Security and Medicare. He always goes around saying, I don't need my Social Security check. Go, well, that's great. You and the other billionaires, send it back. We don't have to change a single number in the program. It doesn't matter. It's too trivial. Knock it down to a million, knock it down to 500,000, knock it down to 200,000. Doesn't matter. If you really want to have an impact on the program, you have to talk about hitting people, I think, by anyone's definition, are very much middle income. The idea they could just get by with much lower checks, cut it in half, they would not see it that way, and I think with some cause. I should also point out, we do have an idea that people should get somewhat of a decent return. Kevin, I'm sure has seen the calculations on this. You take someone who's earned 70, 80,000 a year, not rich by any means, but well above the average in this country. Their Social Security benefit would imply a return, somewhere in order of half a percent, 1%, depending exactly what year they're born, not a very strong real return. It's not zero, so I have something to show, but it's not a great return. Now, if we were to substantially reduce that, they would be getting back less in real dollars than what they paid in. Would we feel good about that? Is that fair? I think there are real problems with that. As I said, I don't see a lot of seniors. I'm certainly willing to grant. We have some that are very comfortable, and if they had a little less money, it wouldn't bother me. But that's not going to have a big impact on the Social Security program. Once we talk about cutting back benefits for people who are very much middle income by everyone's definition, then I have a problem with it. Larry Jacobs: Kevin Hassett, I think all of us would agree that the real challenge in terms of deficits on the healthcare side, and for Medicare, reflects the backdrop of health expenditures. I'm wondering if your views about the sustainability of Medicare, how they've changed in light of the Affordable Care Act, which reduced the subsidies to private insurers and Medicare advantage. Big debate about that, and I'm sure there's some folks here not too happy about it, but in fiscal terms, it reduced some of the costs. Then you've got this pattern, which the CBO actually just reported and it's a much discussed report last week, though this was not part of the headline that the slowdown in the growth of Medicare, they described it as broad and persistent. If you look at spending per beneficiary in Medicare, it rose about 4% between 1985 and 2000. CBO is talking now about 1.5% after controlling for inflation. When you start to look at those changes, does that give you any hope, or do you still remain quite concerned about the sustainability of Medicare? Dean Baker: The key question really is the subset of your question, that there has been a palpable slowing in the growth of health expenses, both for private insurers and for the federal government. It seems like the inflection point was about a decade ago. It's about when the trend seems to have broken. It's accelerated by the recession and if it continues, then the problem, it's still large, but it's significantly smaller than we thought. When we're thinking about the sustainability of Medicare, then what happens to costs? Do they go back to growing as fast as they were when they were really skyrocketing a little bit more than a decade ago, or do they stay at the lower rate? It's a big open question. When someone takes a forecast where historically over the last few years, the CBO has been presuming that the really high cost growth is going to come back. That's probably the prudent risk averse thing for a neutral budget analyst to do.